Macroeconomic Lessons from the Past Decade

Below the fold is a draft of a chapter I’m contributing to an edited volume on aggregate demand and employment. My chapter is supposed to cover macroeconomic policy and employment in the US, with other chapters covering other countries and regions. 

The chapter is mostly based on material I’ve pulished elsewhere, mainly my Roosevelt papers “What Recovery?” and “A New Direction for the Federal Reserve.” My goal was something that summarized the arguments there for an audience of (presumably) heterodox macroeconomists, and that could also be used in the classroom.

There is still time to revise this, so comments/criticisms are very welcome.

*

If nothing else, the decade since 2008 has been an informative one for macroeconomics. The Great Recession and its aftermath have offered a rich new trove of data, have taught several clear lessons, and have posed some new questions. A decade after the worst recession in its modern history, policymakers in the US now confront the question — last faced in the 1990s — of what constitutes full employment and whether supply constraints might be more elastic than previously believed.

In this essay, I lay out three broad lessons that can be drawn from the US economic experience of the past decade. First, aggregate demand remains decisive for unemployment and related aggregate outcomes. A corollary is that fiscal policy remains effective. Second, the effects of demand cannot be limited to “the short run”. The division between a long-run supply-side and a short-run demand-side, while it may be useful analytically, does not work as a description of real world developments. Both the size of the labor force and productivity growth are substantially endogenous to aggregate demand. Third, the conventional tools of monetary policy are inadequate to stabilize output and employment. This inadequacy is often expressed as a problem of the zero lower bound, but the problem is broader than than this.

All three of these lessons were, to some degree, taken aboard by mainstream policymakers and economists in the years after the crisis. It is unclear to what extent there will be any lasting reorientation of macroeconomic policy, especially in the current political environment.

The remainder of this essay discusses these three topics in turn.

1. Demand still drives (un)employment

The decade since the beginning of the recession in December 2007 saw total growth in US employment of 18 percent. This is, by a wide margin, the least growth in employment for any ten-year period since the 1930s. To what extent is this the result of substitution away from labor in production, and to what extent of slower output growth? And to the extent that it is the latter, to what extent is this slower output growth driven by demand versus supply (or structural) factors?

Slow employment growth immediately after a recession has been recognized at least since Okun (1962) as the natural result of employment dynamics in which businesses reduce labor less than proportionately in downturn, leaving a pool of underutilized labor that must be drawn down in the first stage of the recovery. But these dynamics are hard to see in the moment. Slow employment growth following a downturn is repeatedly taken as a sign that structural factors — usually imagined as technological change — have rendered some large fraction of the laborforce permanently unemployable. The 2008-2009 recession was no exception – stories of zero-marginal-product workers, the great recalculation, and so on joined long-standing fears of automation as reasons that unemployment would remain high even as demand recovered. (See for instance Cowen and Lemke 2011)

It is true that unemployment rose somewhat more during the recession itself than the historical Okun’s law relationship would have predicted. This perhaps reflected increase flexibility in US labor markets, which made it easier for employers to reduce staffing as output fell. (Reich 2012) But once output began to rise again, unemployment actually fell faster than the historical relationship with output growth would have implied. So substitution away from labor does not seem to have played any role in the weak labor market of the past decade. The slow growth in output after the expansion is more than sufficient to explain the slow fall in unemployment; there is no need to look to robots or other technological factors to explain persistently high unemployment. (Another way of looking at this: stories about job-destroying automation and so on require an acceleration of productivity growth; but productivity growth has in fact been historically slow.) The Beveridge curve similarly shows a familiar story of labor market slackening and tightening. Apart from the anomalous rise in unemployment in 2010, the strongly correlated movement of the unemployment and vacancy rates suggests unemployment was high simply because employers didn’t need more workers; there is no need to look for reasons why some part of the population has become permanently unemployable. (Konczal and Jayadev 2011)

The experience of the last decade offers no obvious support for a focus on labor-market interventions to bring down unemployment, whether the further liberalization proposed from the right or the federal jobs guarantee proposed from the left. To recreate the labor market performance of the late 1990s, recreating late-90s growth should be sufficient. As Bivens (2017) argues, a “high-pressure economy” will not only boost output and employment, the historical record suggests it will disproportionately benefit those at the back of the hiring queue.

The natural next question is whether slow growth is due to supply or demand constraints. There are several reasons to think that it is mostly or entirely demand. First, the failure to close the gap with the pre-recession trend; second, the absence of any of the usual macroeconomic indicators of supply constraints; and third, the weakness of a demographic explanation for slow employment growth.

By official measures, the output gap took eight years to fully close, with output reaching potential by the second quarter of 2017. But this closing of the output gap was entirely due to downward revisions of potential output. Using estimates made in 2008, 2017 output remained 11 points below potential – a larger gap than at the bottom of the recession in 2009. (Mason 2017) Comparing current per-capita output to the pre-2008 trend implies a similar gap. This is by far the largest deviation from trend in the post-1945 period.

The deviation of GDP from its long-run trend is already a problem for claims that the economy is now operating at full potential. There is little question that the financial crisis, collapse of the housing market, mass unemployment and general fear and uncertainty of the recession period itself depressed aggregate demand—that is, they reduced households’ and businesses’ desired spending. But if the sharp fall in output of 2008-2009 was driven by demand-side factors, logically there should have been some bounce back once those conditions depressing desired spending were removed.

The most obvious supply-side explanation for the slower growth of the past decade is a deceleration in laborforce growth. Laborforce growth is often regarded as a straightforward matter of demographics, plus some equally slow-moving institutional factors like migration and norms around women’s participation in paid work. It is certainly true that the age distribution of the US population has been shifting upward and that, historically, laborforce participation rates peak decline with age above 50 or so. But a careful examination of the data does not support the view that demographics explains the the slowdown in output growth.

Between 2000 and 2016, the U.S. employment-population ratio declined by about five points, of which four points came since 2007. If we group the population by age and sex, we find that, three points (2.5 since 2007) of that decline have reflected lower participation rates within demographic groups, while two points (1.5 since 2007) reflect changes in the composition of the population. (Mason 2017) The conclusion that at most half the decline in labor force participation is attributable to aging is shared by most studies of this question, including the Council of Economic Advisors (CEA 2014) and Dantas and Wray (2017). At the same time, however, education levels have been rising, and education is positively correlated with laborforce participation. If we include education as a demographic variable, we find that these two effects almost exactly cancel out, leaving only a minor demographic effect — less than half a point out of the five point total decline. (Mason 2017)

While the aging of the population can, in an accounting sense, “explain” close to half of the decline in laborforce participation in an accounting sense, we should be wary of taking this to mean that the decline was inevitable or independent of demand conditions. Variation in laborforce participation by age is not especially stable over time, and in fact shifted significantly over the past 15 years. The modest fall in overall laborforce participation reflects from much larger offsetting changes in particular age groups: Participation among those 55 and older has increased by 5 points, while among those 24 and younger it has fallen by 10 points. These large within-group changes make it clear that participation rates by age are not a hard structural constraint.

More broadly, there is no reason to imagine a fixed, “normal” participation rate for a given demographic group. The large increase in women’s labor force participation between the 1950s and 1980s, for instance, would not have been predictable on demographic grounds. And while the postwar U.S. has not seen sustained demand shocks on the level of the Great Recession, history does suggest that large demand shifts can have large, persistent effects on labor force participation rates. The fall in employment in the 1930s, for instance, reflected not only elevated unemployment rates but also a large fall in measured participation rates; participation then rose even more sharply with the “effectively unlimited labor demand” during the war (Mathy 2015). Arguments implying that the U.S. today is at potential would, in 1940, have ruled out the large increase in employment that took place during the war.

Assessing the relative importance of demand conditions versus autonomous technological factors in the slow growth of labor productivity is more difficult. But if we take a step back and look at the overall macroeconomic situation, it is hard to avoid the conclusion that there has been a large and persistent fall in desired spending, i.e. aggregate demand.

Most heterodox as well as mainstream macroeconomic models suggess that while declines in either aggregate supply and demand growth will be associated with decelerations in output, the latter will be associated with slower price growth as well, while the former will be associated with fast price level growth. Supply constraints also imply an increase in the relative price of the scarce factors, so to the extent that the negative supply shock is supposed to include a demographic component, we should see a rising rather than a falling wage share. Furthermore, a negative supply shock does not, in itself explain why desired spending fell along with it. The conventional view is that policy must adjust in a contractionary direction in response to a negative supply shock, to bring the desired path of spending down to the new, lower path of potential output. Yet both monetary and fiscal policy during the recovery have been exceptionally expansionary.

To believe that the slow growth over the past decade is primarily a supply-side phenomenon, we need not just one but a series of coincidences. Just as the economy recovered from the financial crisis, there was a steep slowdown in employment driven by demographic change. And at the same time, there was an unrelated slowdown in the pace of technological innovation. In addition, there must still have been an independent fall in demand to explain why the negative shocks to labor and technology did not lead to higher inflation that the textbook predicts. And the timing has to be perfect: if the demographic decline in the labor force had come a few years earlier, there would have been no rise in unemployment during the recession, while if it had had come a few years later, we would still be looking at high unemployment today. Since we need a fall in demand in any case, Occam’s razor suggests we should prefer stories in which that drives everything else: A weak labor market discourages labor force participation, while weak demand in product markets and stagnant wages together discourage productivity-boosting innovation. Rather than a precisely synchronized series of unobservable shocks, this story requires just one, which we have in fact observed in the form of the end of the housing boom and the financial crisis.

The need to look at the full macroeconomic picture to distinguish supply from demand was expressed forcefully by DeLong and Summers (2012). They argue that interpretations of the fall in GDP as a decline in potential are missing an “elementary signal extraction point”: a fall in potential output implies a simultaneous fall in production and increase in inflation. Just as a simultaneous fall in the price and quantity sold of a given good can’t be explained by a fall in supply of it but only by a fall in demand for it, a simultaneous slowdown in production and prices in the economy as a whole suggests a fall in aggregate demand, not in aggregate supply.

If weak demand is responsible for slow output growth, it follows that increasing the flow of spending is both necessary and sufficient to raise output and employment. This suggests a larger role for fiscal policy, and indeed a range of both mainstream and heterodox empirical studies over the past decade have found large, positive fiscal multipliers. This is one of the few areas where the crisis seems to have led to a significant shift in mainstream macroeconomics, at least in its more policy-oriented precincts, with a broad recognition that fiscal multipliers had been systematically underestimated in the past. (Blanchard and Leigh 2013) Mainstream policymakers are now at least receptive to a “new view” in which fiscal policy has an important role in stabilizing output and employment. (Furman 2016)

A further question is whether fiscal policy, even if effective, may be limited by the need to issue new debt to finance it. A decade ago, this was unquestioned in the mainstream, and widely accepted among heterodox writers as well. Today there is less consensus on this point. One school of heterodox thought, which has gained increasing prominence over the decade, holds that for a country like the United States, the existing public debt is never a constraint on fiscal policy. (Juniper et al. 2015) One need not accept this categorical claim, however, to believe that for the US and other advanced countries, the debt ratio is not a serious constraint in practice. First, even if the idea of limited fiscal space is accepted in principle, it is hard to find in the data. Early in the decade strong claims were made for a hard tipping point (often 90 percent of GDP) beyond which higher public debt would sharply and reliably depresses growth. But the studies on which these claims were based were effectively debunked, and they seem to have receded from view. (Herndon et al 2013) Meanwhile countries throughout the advanced world have seen debt-GDP ratios rise to postwar highs while interest rates have remained at historical lows. Second, expansionary fiscal policy need not lead to a higher debt ratio, if interest rates fall or nominal growth rates rise. (Conversely even large fiscal surpluses can be associated with a rising debt ratio if nominal income falls, as has been dramatically shown in Greece.) If interest rates on public debt are lower on average than growth rates, then any fiscal position is sustainable, in the sense that the debt ratio will always converge to a finite value. There has been increasing recognition over the past decade that the historical evolution of debt ratios, in the US and elsewhere, has been driven at least as much by the interest-growth rate differential as by changes in fiscal policy. If a central bank can control the interest rate on public debt — an entirely orthodox assumption — then it should be possible for the budget authorities to freely conduct fiscal policy while the central bank maintains the debt ratio at whatever level is considered socially desirable. (Mason and Jayadev 2018) Finally, even if the interest rate is exogenously fixed, expansionary fiscal policy need not raise the debt ratio if its effects persist beyond the period in which it is undertaken. Even a modest spillover into future years is sufficient for increased public spending to “pay for itself” in the sense of resulting in a lower long-term debt ratio. (DeLong and Summers 2012)

2. There may be no economically meaningful long run

The conventional distinction between a demand-determined short-run and supply-determined long run hinges on the idea that the economy’s productive potential evolves independently of the flow of spending. Analytically, this requires a sharply-defined hierarchy of “fast” and “slow” variables, such that the latter can be treated as exogenously fixed with respect to the former. Conceptually, it requires us to believe both that technological change, laborforce growth, and other supply-side variables evolve independently of current employment and output; and that demand reliably converges to supply-determined potential.  Empirically, it requires some strategy to measure potential output independently of current output.

On the empirical level, the traditional approach has been to use some measure of trend, such as the popular Hodrick-Prescott filter, such that longer-term movements in output are attributed to potential while shorter-term movements are attributed to demand. This is the procedure used to produce most official estimates of potential output. [FN: This is true of the US estimate, albeit indirectly: While the estimate itself is derived from a production function, key parameters, such as total factor productivity, are derived from a trend. (CBO 2001)] The obvious flaw in this approach, as a number of critics have pointed out, is that it turns sustained deviations in output growth into shifts in potential by assumption. If output growth slows for whatever reason, trend- or filter-based measures will necessarily show a similar deceleration in potential output. (Rosnick 2016) The Hodrick-Prescott filter has defects beyond the generic issues with trend-based estimates of potential — in particular, it puts disproportionate weight on recent observations. (Hamilton forthcoming) Alternative measures of potential suggest a much larger gap between current output and potential than the official measures. (Coibon et al. 2017) But the problem exists with any trend based measures of potential, unless one has decided ex ante that demand effects cannot be persistent.

Conceptually, there are good reasons to doubt that growth in the laborforce or in labor productivity can be safely regarded as independent of demand conditions. Hysteresis in labor markets is well-supported empirically and at least somewhat accepted in mainstream theory. A common definition is offered by the New York Fed: “extended periods of high unemployment [that] lead to skill losses among workers, reducing human capital and lowering future output.” (Acharya et al. 2016) A substantial effect of unemployment, especially long-term employment, on future employment and income prospects is plausible and well-attested. While the postwar U.S. has not seen sustained demand shocks on the level of the Great Recession, history does suggest that large demand shifts can have large, persistent effects on labor force participation rates. The fall in employment in the 1930s, for instance, reflected not only elevated unemployment rates but also a large fall in measured participation rates; participation then rose even more sharply with the “effectively unlimited labor demand” during the war. (Mathy 2018)

Persistent effects of demand on productivity growth are less discussed in the mainstream. One common argument for seeing the productivity slowdown as a negative technology shock is that it is simply the flipside of the positive shock of the “tech boom” of the 1990s. In this view, the fact that the slowdown in productivity was not predicted before the recession should not be seen as evidence that it is the result of the recession. Rather, it is simply the correction of an earlier, mistaken extrapolation from a period of exceptional productivity growth. (Gordon 2016).

On the other hand, the decline in the labor share is often understood to reflect a change in productive technology that encourages substitution of capital for labor. This may or may not be a reasonable way to think about the longer-term trend in factor shares. But it faces obvious problems as applied to the past decade in the U.S. (and other countries with similar experiences), as this is the same period that writers like Gordon (2016) say has seen a decline in productivity growth thanks to the exhaustion of information technology. In isolation, stories that explain a falling wage share by rapid technological progress, and falling productivity growth by slow technological progress, may each seem plausible. But both cannot be true simultaneously.

A link from demand to productivity has long been discussed in heterodox work, often under the rubric of Verdoorn’s law. Besides the pure increasing-returns story, a number of possible mechanisms might link productivity growth to demand conditions. A brief list of possible links would include:

–  Less pseudo employment. In any economy, there are activities that are formally classified as employment but are not work in any substantive sense. Robinson (1937, p. 61-643) described these kinds of pseudo-jobs “disguised unemployment.”  Her examples were someone who gathers firewood in a poor country, or sells pencils on street corners in a richer one. Work in family businesses, self-employment and commission-based work might also fall in this category. (One of the few attempts to measure this kind of disguised unemployment is Eatwell (1997).) These activities absorb people who are unable to find formal jobs; the marginal product of additional workers here is very low. If higher demand draws people from this kind of disguised unemployment back into regular jobs, measured productivity will rise.

– More capital-intensive production. For those accustomed to thinking in terms of a production function, the most natural explanation for changes in labor productivity is changes in the capital stock per worker. For heterodox writers, skeptical of the idea of a physical stock of capital and more attuned to the sociological complexity of the production process, it is not a simple matter of adding a little more  capital and a little less labor to the bouillabaisse, in Leijonhufvud’s (1986) memorable metaphor. But there are still many cases where it is not unreasonable to imagine a production process carried out with more (or better) machines, implying higher output per worker. Insofar as investment responds to demand conditions, this will show up as a demand-driven change in productivity. The accelerator principle that “investment generally follows overall demand” has seen some revival in mainstream policy discussions. (Furman 2015)

– Innovation in response to demand and costs. Higher wages not only lead businesses to adopt new technology, they may also lead to a redirection of social resources toward developing less labor-intensive techniques of production. In addition, innovation is typically embodied in new capital goods and new firms, rather than from improvements of existing ones. Investment is highly cyclical, and it is much easier to start a new business in a boom than in a recession.

– Employment shifts toward higher-productivity sectors and firms. Aggregate productivity may rise even if output per worker is constant in each individual industry, if there is a shift in employment toward higher-productivity industries. This may happen for one of two reasons: First, higher wages will disproportionately raise costs for more labor- intensive sectors. Second, the more income-elastic sectors may also be higher-productivity ones. Manufacturing, in particular, is both more income-elastic and higher productivity than services. Meanwhile, within a given industry firms employ technology and capital equipment of a range of vintages and efficiencies. To grow, more productive businesses must bid away workers and other inputs from incumbent firms, requiring a wage significantly above the going rate. In this sense, higher wages are an integral part of productivity growth.

– Increasing returns.  It may be that output per worker rises at the firm, industry or economy-wide level when the amount being produced increases. It’s worth noting that increasing returns is an area in which the intuition of people with economics training diverges sharply from people in the business and policy worlds. In many contexts outside economic theory, it is obvious that unit costs fall as more is produced.

While labor productivity — and the conditions of production in general — are strictly segregated from demand and business cycle analysis in the mainstream, heterodox writers have long explored the possibility that output per worker might systematically vary with demand. (Storm and Naastepad 2012) It is important, however, to think carefully about what kind of substantive relationship might underlie a model’s formal relationship between output and productivity. For example, if we imagine the link operating through higher capital per worker (in whatever sense), we would expect that low unemployment could yield a one-time shift to a higher level of output per worker. But if we imagine the link operating through a more favorable environment for innovation, then low unemployment might be associated with persistently faster productivity growth. General formulations like “a system that is growing fast is forced to innovate” (Jeon and Vernengo 2008), while pointing in the right direction, need to be grounded in sociologically rich, empirically based accounts of the concrete linkages between demand and productivity growth.

Whatever the exact mechanisms, if demand conditions can have persistent effects on labor supply and/or productivity, this has serious implications for both policy and theory.

On the policy side, most straightforwardly, it means more space for expansionary policy. Low measured unemployment rates are not a sign of approaching supply constraints if the laborforce itself is highly elastic. The elasticity of labor supply and productivity helps explain why measured unemployment has been able to fall to historically low levels without, as of mid-2018, any rise in inflation.  Endogenous supply growth also implies higher costs for demand shortfalls, and lower costs for overshooting supply constraints. Negative demand gaps imply lower output and employment in future years, as well as this one, while the inflation and other costs of overheating will be offset by higher output in future years, as aggregate supply adjusts upward. This means that policy should worry more about closing output gaps and less about inflation, a view that has made some headway in policy discussions. For example, Blanchard, Cerutti and Summers (2015) observe: “To the extent that hysteresis is present, it implies that deviations in output from its optimal level are much longer lasting and thus more costly than usually assumed. The implication is straightforward, namely that monetary policy should react more strongly to output movements, relative to inflation.”

The presence of hysteresis and what we might call anti-hysteresis (demand-induced increases in potential output) does not merely favor more expansionary policy, it also complicate policy decisions. The delegation of macroeconomic policy to independent central banks was based on the premise that managing aggregate demand did not involve any substantial tradeoffs, and so did not pose political questions. A central building block of the modern consensus view was that there is no meaningful tradeoff between inflation and unemployment — attempting to raise demand beyond potential will produce at best small and transitory increases in output and employment, while permanently raising inflation. In a world with hysteresis, the opposite is true: Raising demand above (current or short-run) potential will produce only temporary inflation, until supply catches up; but it will produce permanent gains in output. (Ball 2009) In this case there is no avoiding the tradeoff between the policy goals of price stability and maximum employment and output.

Analytically, the first casualty of hysteresis is the idea of a labor supply. Instead, we may imagine a hierarchy of proximity to employment. The short-term unemployed are the closest, followed by the longer-term unemployed, employed people seeking additional work, discouraged workers, workers disfavored by employers due to ethnicity, credentials, etc. Beyond this are people whose claim on the social product is not normally exercised by paid labor – retired people, the disabled, fulltime caregivers – but might  come to be if labor market conditions were sufficiently favorable. Even further out, migration (both inward and outward) is also responsive to some degree to labor market conditions. There is no place within this gradient to draw a line around “the laborforce”. Transitions between unemployment and employment are not today — if they ever were — sufficiently more responsive to labor-market conditions than transitions between other statuses to make the concept meaningful.  Of course this is not news, but what we have learned is that this fuzziness is not a second-order detail that can be safely abstracted from. Formally, it seems, we should think not of an exogenous labor supply, but of a labor supply that is more or less elastic in response to labor-market conditions.

Similarly, technological change must also be thought of as responsive to demand conditions, as well as to investment — which itself is responsive to demand via the accelerator principle. To capture this, we cannot make production technology a fixed parameter.

Endogenizing labor supply and production technology may seem technically straightforward, even if it requires modifying many widely-used macro models. But it poses a deeper problem. The long run in economic models means, formally, a length of time for some set of endogenous variables (e.g. the capital stock) to have fully adjusted to the exogenous ones. But in a world where labor and technology are responsive to demand conditions, it is not clear what are the exogenous variables we should think of the long-run position as being adjusted to. It may not be sensible to think of macroeconomic variables as being partitioned into fast and slow ones, such that the latter can be treated as exogenous for the behavior of the latter. Employment, the laborforce, output, the capital stock and technology may all adjust to each other, on comparable time scales. Such a system will of course still have dynamics which can be formally modeled. But it will have no economically meaningful long run.

Again, there is nothing new here in principle. But what we have learned is that the division between endogenous and exogenous, or fast and slow, macroeconomic variables commonly used in heterodox as well as mainstream work, may not work even as a first approximation – it may abstract away from essential features of the developments we wish to explain. In this case, we may conclude that the techniques of formal modeling are best reserved for short-run, static analysis only. When we wish to discuss the longer term evolution of capitalist economies, over periods of decades to centuries, we may do better to skip the systems of equations, and focus on concrete historical description and accounting.

3. Conventional monetary policy is insufficient to manage aggregate demand. 

A third lesson of the past decade is that central banks’ macroeconomic role cannot be reduced to setting a single interest rate. This is both because the interest-rate instrument is inadequate to hit the conventional price-stability target, and because it is now clear that macroeconomic stabilization involves a number of targets, which are not equivalent to each other.

Before 2008, both academic macroeconomics and macroeconomic policy were strongly committed to the notion that conventional monetary policy, operating through a single overnight interest rate, was fully sufficient to offset any fluctuations in aggregate demand. The complacent view of future Obama administration CEA chair Christina Romer, offered on the verge of the crisis, is typical: “The Federal Reserve is directly responsible for … the virtual disappearance of the business cycle in the last 25 years… The story of stabilization policy in the last quarter century is one of amazing success. … We have seen a glorious counterrevolution in the ideas and conduct of short-run stabilization policy.” (Romer 2017) Macroeconomics textbooks at both the undergraduate and graduate levels were organized around models in which a central bank setting a short-run interest rate according to an appropriate policy rule would fully offset demand shocks, and ensure an optimal adjustment to supply shocks. To a lesser but still substantial extent, macroeconomic policy debates were also focused on a single short-run interest rate instrument.

While this narrow vision of macroeconomic policymaking appeared to work reasonably well in the U.S. and other developed countries in the two decades or so before 2007, today it is clear that it is an inadequate description of what central banks have been doing, let alone what they should be doing. Careful students of monetary policymaking have always had doubts about the straightforward transmission mechanism linking the policy rate to broader macro outcomes. (Hannsgen 2004) But the crisis gave those doubts wider purchase. By 2011, Olivier Blanchard  (then chief economist of the IMF) could write:

“Before the crisis, mainstream economists and policymakers had … convinced ourselves that there was one target, inflation. There was one instrument, the policy rate. And that was basically enough to get things done. If there is one lesson to be drawn from this crisis, it is that this construction wasn’t right… The fact is that there are many targets and there are many instruments.” (Blanchard 2011)

The most obvious reason for skepticism about the old model of monetary policy is the manifest weakness of the interest rate instrument. The most straightforward evidence for this is the depth of the downturn itself, and the weakness of the recovery that followed, despite what was, by conventional measures, exceptionally expansionary policy. By the BEA’s official measures, the cumulative output gap in the decade 2008-2017 amounted to 25 percent of GDP, the largest cumulative gap of any postwar cycle, making a mockery of the idea of central-bank driven “great moderation.” And if the ideas of hysteresis discussed in the previous section are valid, then the true gap was even larger. This failure is often discussed in terms of the “zero lower bound” of the policy rate. But this is a one-sided way of looking at it: We must also ask why rates below zero were needed in the first place. As a matter of logic, if a much larger than expected reduction in rates is needed to keep the economy at full employment, then either the demand shocks are larger than previously believed, or the effect of a given change in rates is smaller (or of course both). These underlying conditions need to be a focus of policy discussions, and not just mechanisms for moving the policy rate (farther) below zero.

It’s important to keep in mind that the large negative output gaps of 2008-2011 came while the policy rate was at 0, compared with 5.25 percent at the start of the recession, federal deficits reached 10 percent of GDP, and the trade balance had moved several points toward surplus. This implies that the underlying fall in demand was larger than the ultimate fall in output. If we accept conventional estimates of the fiscal multiplier and interest-elasticity of output, like those of Hervé et al (2010), that implies a fall in autonomous private demand on the order of one-third of total private expenditure, over a period of two years. We should not rule out that private demand is this unstable. But such an large implied fall in demand should also lead us to consider that the sensitivity of output to changes in the policy rate may be smaller than previously believed, perhaps close to zero.

One reason why changes in the policy rate might not have a strong effect on real activity is that it is only weakly linked to market interest rates, particularly the long rates that are most important for real activity. Over time, spreads between the policy rate and longer and riskier rates have grown both wider and more variable. (Mason and Jayadev 2015a) In the most recent recession, the Fed reduced the policy rate from 5.25 percent in July 2007 to 0 by December 2008. Yet it would take another two years for 10-year Treasury bonds to fall even 1.5 points from their 2007 level. Baa corporate bond rates, a good indicator of rates facing large private borrowers, actually rose as the Fed cut rates during the crisis; as late as mid-2011, after more than two and half years of policy rates at zero, corporate bond rates were within half a point of their pre-crisis levels. The Keynesian tradition offers a number of explanations for the independence of long rates from short rates, going back to Keynes’ observation that the long rate is highly conventional phenomenon whose current rate is based mainly on market participants’ beliefs about its own future value. But whatever the reason for the disconnect, it suggests that if monetary policy is to affect credit conditions for private borrowers, it cannot rely on the overnight rate but must target long rates directly. For Keynes, an “offer by the central bank to buy and sell at stated prices gilt-edged bonds of all maturities, in place of the single bank rate for short- term bills” would be “the most important practical improvement which can be made in the technique of monetary management.” (Keynes 2012, p. 206)  There is precedent for the Fed targeting longer rates: Between 1942 and 1947, the Fed successfully maintained a 2.5 percent ceiling on long-term government bonds. (Hetzel 2001)

A second set of arguments for a broader conception of monetary policy going forward is that the macroeconomic outcomes of concern to the central bank cannot be reduced to a single target. Prior to 2008, textbook and, for the most part, policy macroeconomics bas based on the idea of a “divine coincidence”. (Blanchard 2016) The same level of demand would result in output at its highest sustainable level, low and stable inflation, and full employment. Formally, this can be assured by definition: Assuming there is some kind of relationship between output, employment and inflation, potential output and full employment can be simply defined as the levels consistent with inflation at target. But the formalism is based, implicitly or explicitly, on a substantive claim about the economy: That most of the variation between the three aggregates is shared, and that the levels of output and employment derived from the formula conform to the conceptions of policymakers and the broader public about acceptable rates of unemployment and growth. The widely-discussed “flattening” of the Phillips curve over the past decade has made this claim less viable. The stability of inflation not far below the Fed’s 2 percent target during the extended period of high unemployment after 2008 makes it clear that hitting the price stability target does not imply an acceptable employment performance. Conversely, the more recent fall in unemployment without any acceleration in inflation suggests that if the central bank continues to respond strongly to unemployment, it may be pursuing an objective other than its stated ones.

An obvious alternative reaction function is suggested by the familiar accounting identity:

 percentage nominal wage growth = inflation + productivity growth + percent change in the wage share

If the central bank targets wage growth even in the absence of a link with inflation, then by definition it must be seeking to prevent a rise in either productivity growth or the wage share. While the former is implausible, the latter is not – there is a long history of public and private statements by central bankers that suggest a rising wage share would be regarded as undesirable, regardless of its effects on inflation. (Mitchell and Erickson 2015) This evolution appears to have gone farther in Europe than in the US, given the replacement of the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment with the Non-Accelerating Wage Rate of Unemployment as a guide for policy; the elevation of competitiveness alongside price stability as a macroeconomic argument for wage restraint; and the focus on real unit labor costs — the latter being simply an obfuscated way of describing the labor share, to which it is identically equal. (Felipe and Kumar 2011) In the US, so far, the rhetoric of monetary policy has more consistently maintained that wage increases are undesirable only insofar as they herald rising inflation; but this will grow harder to sustain if the Fed continues to raise rates in response to low unemployment in the absence of any inflation signal.

As noted in the previous section, the presence of hysteresis also creates problems for the divine coincidence. If labor supply and/pr productivity growth vary with unemployment, we can no longer assume that above-target inflation implies a positive output gap that can only be closed by lower demand. If allowed to persist, a positive output gap may instead eventuate in increased supply. This creates a challenging tradeoff for monetary policy.

Additional problems for orthodoxy arise when we look at policy at a more disaggregated level. Whether or not they reliably affect real activity, changes in the policy rate certainly move asset prices and debt stocks. The asset price effect has gotten more discussion, with financial stability entering the lexicon as an argument for higher rates. (Leijonhufvud 2009) But the latter may be important. Historically, the interest-rate growth-rate differential has been more important for changes in the federal debt-GDP ratio than changes in the fiscal position. (Kogan et al 2015) This is even more true of household debt. Indeed, the entire rise in household debt-income ratios since 1980 can be explained in accounting terms by the rise in effective interest rates relative to nominal income growth. CITE US If debt ratios and/or asset prices are a concern for policymakers, they must be taken into consideration by rate-setters at the Fed.

To the extent that monetary policy does affect real activity, it is unlikely to be through changes in “the” interest rate faced by the economy as a whole, but in the availability of credit for specific sectors and activities. The inadequacy of the conventional interest rate channel of policy has long been recognized by practitioners, even if it has yet to make its way into policy. (Bernanke and Gertler 1995) Housing, in particular, has been relatively more sensitive to policy, with mortgage rates more closely linked to the policy rate and mortgage borrowing moving more with interest rate changes. The disproportionate sensitivity of housing to monetary policy may be the main reason why policy is not completely ineffectual; but it also means that policy changes are affecting the share of output devoted to housing as well as the overall level of output. Similarly, the Fed’s exceptional interventions to support the housing market may have been undertaken to protect the credit system as a whole, but they have the effect of favoring credit into housing rather than to other sectors. It may be time to frankly acknowledge that monetary policy affects the direction as well as level of activity, and ask what kinds of activity are most deserving of support. It might, for instance, be wiser to channel credit toward decarbonization rather than toward the single-family housing sector.

The financial crisis itself also calls into question the existing conduct of monetary policy, in two ways. First it demonstrated (not for the first time) the possibility of massive asset bubbles, and banking crises in their wake. The concerns this raises for monetary policy are obviously exacerbated if one believes monetary policy operates in large part through asset prices; and if one believes, as famously suggested by Summers (2014),  that the advanced economies face a secular shortfall in demand, or secular stagnation, such that full employment is possible only in the presence of inflated asset prices. Second, the possibility of what certainly appears, ex post, as widespread mispricing of assets and misallocation of credit, should raise doubts about the private financial system’s ability to direct credit even in normal times. Krugman (2016) suggests that this broader point about the efficiency of financial markets should be one of the main lessons of the crisis. The experience of the past decade suggests:

“… a broader rationale for policy activism than most macroeconomists—even self- proclaimed Keynesians—have generally offered in recent decades. Most of them… have seen the role for policy as pretty much limited to stabilizing aggregate demand. Correcting asset markets when they go wrong wasn’t part of the mandate, because who were policymakers to claim that they were smarter than private investors? Once we admit that there can be big asset mispricing due to liquidity and collateral constraints, however, the case for intervention becomes much stronger…”

Whatever one’s priors about the relative merits of private versus public direction of finance and investment, the experience of 2008-2009 should shift them in favor of the latter. And if the private financial system cannot be trusted to direct society’s surplus toward the most valuable uses, then, in the absence of other public financial institutions, central banks must play a more active role.

For all these reasons, it seems unlikely that monetary policy in the future will fit the textbook model of setting a single overnight interest rate. Quantitative easing, forward guidance and, probably, larger and more heterogeneous asset holdings, are already widely accepted as permanent parts of monetary policy for the foreseeable future. (Friedman 2014) But it is unlikely that these relatively modest changes to orthodoxy will be enough for central banks to relaibly achieve their goals. With respect to quantitative easing, even positive assessments of its effects suggest that it is too weak to play more than a supporting role in macroeconomic stabilization. One recent survey of empirical studies of QE finds that the median estimate is that purchases of bonds equal to 10 percent of GDP would reduce long rates by eight tenths of a point.  (Gagnon 2016) This is not trivial, but it is quite small relative to the program’s size, and to the requirements of macroeconomic stabilization. Iorward guidance appears even weaker; indeed, the idea that central banks can influence economic outcomes today by announcing policy changes somewhere in the future is “more theological than practical.” (Friedman 2014)  It is based on models in which agents have qualitatively greater knowledge of the future than is available in the real world, and in which they are able to act freely on this knowledge thanks to the absence of exactly the kinds of financial frictions that make monetary policy necessary in the first place.

The implication is that central banks must be political. There is no way around weighing a variety of social priorities, and making judgments about the social value of the various activities in need of financing. Even if aggregate liquidity or average interest could be reliably set at the “right” level, many individual borrowers would still get too little credit, and a few would get too much. As Stiglitz (2013) frankly puts it, “Governments and central banks need to have explicit programs to encourage lending to certain groups/sectors that are underserved.”

From the perspective of the pre-2008 consensus this sounds radical, but in a longer view it is not as much a departure. Historically, macroeconomic demand management by central banks has involved a much broader range of both goals and tools compared to the pre-2008 orthodoxy. (Epstein 2013). In the years after 2008, many central bankers have recognized that It is likely that future crises and/or prolonged demand shortfalls will require experimentation with a broader range of targets and instruments.  In the words of the former Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee member Adam Posen (2012):

“… you only need to look back at monetary history to see the obvious: central banks have engaged in extended periods of administrative guidance, of doing very active directed lending in particular sectors, and especially of engaging in market operations on financial assets other than government securities… It is quite literally a prehistoric argument to assert that central banks are engaged in experimental, unprecedented, or somehow scandalous and dangerous policy maneuvers today.”

During the financial crisis of 2007-2009, the Fed created special facilities to support lending in a range of other markets. To support markets for securitized auto loans and credit card loans, the Fed created the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) in November 2008, which purchased nearly $50 billion of such securities. The Fed also created lending facilities to provide support to commercial paper, money-market funds, and securities broker-dealers (Price 2012). While conceived of as emergency measures, similar programs could be adopted on an ongoing basis if there is reason to believe that the normal allocation of credit is inconsistent with social priorities, or with financial stability, or with the Fed’s other macroeconomic objectives. In the long run, making the Fed a more reliable steward of the macroeconomy will require a reconceptualization of the its place in the financial system. The clean separation of monetary policy, carried out by an independent central bank based on a simple policy rule, from other aspects of macroeconomic policy conducted by the elected government, is no longer viable—if it ever was.

Conclusion

Eighty years after Keynes first stated it in its modern form, the principle of aggregate demand remains profoundly subversive of received economic wisdom. Orthodox economic theory, in both its textbook and cutting-edge incarnations, is based on a framework in which economic problems are essentially about the allocation of scarce resources among competing ends. If output is constrained by demand, then this framework is inapplicable. A demand-constrained economy is operating far from the “real” supply constraints analyzed by orthodoxy, if indeed these constraints exist at all. Real resources are not scarce. The central economic problem is not allocation, but coordination. As a corollary, if the economy suffers from large-scale coordination problems, markets are evidently inadequate to coordinate our collective productive activity. All of this is profoundly unsettling to those brought up in the orthodox economics tradition.

Within mainstream macroeconomics, the “freshwater” or real-business cycle school seeks to expunge demand entirely by explaining even short-run fluctuations in output and employment by shifts in real productive capacities. The more policy-oriented parts of orthodoxy cannot dispense with demand entirely, so they seek to quarantine it as a purely short-run phenomenon that can be safely left to the management of the central bank.

The experience of the past decade suggests that demand cannot be so easily removed from its place at the center of the macroeconomic stage. Despite efforts to explain the behavior of employment in terms of demographics, technological change or other “real” or supply-side phenomena, it is hard to make sense of labor-market developments of the past ten years except in terms of shifts in aggregate spending. Nor can we safely assume that demand fluctuations are purely short-term, so that the long-run evolution of the economy can be analyzed in terms of the real dynamics of accumulation and exogenous technological and demographic change. The past decade’s weak growth in employment, productivity and output appears to be due to a demand gap which has already persisted well beyond any reasonable “short run,” and shows no sign of closing. A third lesson of the past decade is that macroeconomic policy cannot be reduced to setting a single short-term interest rate. It is now clear that the policy rate is a much weaker tool for stabilizing demand than had been believed in the years before 2008. It is also clear that in attempting to stabilize the path of output and employment, the central bank must also consider the effects of its actions on asset markets, the distribution of income and the composition of spending.

The experience of the past decade has been taken, with reason, as vindication by writers in the Post Keynesian and broader heterodox macroeconomics traditions. But they also pose challenges for heterodox approaches. Heterodox as well as mainstream writers often work in terms of a single economy-wide interest rate, which is supposed to have a decisive effect on the level of activity. The past decade suggests we should treat this idea with some skepticism. The short-run – long-run distinction is also widely used in heterodox macroeconomics. This is part of a longer term shift within Keynesian macroeconomics away from cyclical fluctuations toward models of long-run growth. One lesson for heterodox macroeconomists may be that that this shift in attention has been carried too far. More broadly, the puzzles posed by the past decade’s developments may be best approached by stepping back from highly aggregated formal models toward a more concrete level of analysis.

References

Aaronson, S., Cajner, T., Fallick, B., Galbis-Reig, F., Smith, C. & Wascher, W. (2014), ‘Labor force participation: recent developments and future prospects’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2014(2), 197–275.

Ball, L. M. (2009), ‘Hysteresis in unemployment: old and new evidence’, National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 14818.

Bernanke, B. S. & Gertler, M. (1995), ‘Inside the black box: The credit channel of monetary policy transmission’, The Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(4), 27–48.

Bivens, J. (2017), ‘A high-pressure economy can help boost productivity and provide even more room to run for the recovery’, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC .

Blanchard, O. (2011), ‘Monetary policy in the wake of the crisis,’ IMF, Macro Conference. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2011/res/pdf/ob2presentation.pdf.

Blanchard, O. (2016), ‘The Phillips curve: Back to the’60s?’, American Economic Review 106(5), 31–34.

Blanchard, O., Cerutti, E. & Summers, L. (2015), ‘Inflation and activity: Two explorations and their monetary policy implications’, National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 21726.

Council of Economic Advisors. 2014. “The labor force participation rate since 2007.” Washington, D.C.: Executive Office of the President of the United States. http://scholar.harvard.edu/files/stock/files/labor_ force_participation.pdf

Congressional Budget Office. 2007. ‘The budget and economic outlook: Fiscal years 2008 to 2017.’ Washington, D.C.: Congressional Budget Office.

Blanchard, O. J. & Leigh, D. (2013), ‘Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers’, American Economic Review 103(3), 117–20.

Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y. & Ulate, M. (2017), ‘The cyclical sensitivity in estimates of potential output’, National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 23580.

Cowen, T. & Lemke, J. (2011), ‘10 percent unemployment forever?’, Foreign Policy, January 6 2011.

DeLong, J. Bradford and Lawrence H. Summers. 2012. ‘Fiscal policy in a depressed economy’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, 233-297.

Eatwell, John. 1997. ‘Effective demand and disguised unemployment.’ In Michie J. and Grieve Smith J., eds, Employment and Economic Performance, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 76-94.

Epstein, Gerald. 2013. ‘Developmental central banking: Winning the future by updating a page from the past’, Review of Keynesian Economics, 1 (3) 273–287.

Dantas, F. & Wray, L. R. (2017), ‘Full employment: Are we there yet?’, Public Policy Brief, Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.

Felipe, J. & Kumar, U. (2014), ‘Unit labor costs in the eurozone: the competitiveness debate again’, Review of Keynesian Economics 2(4), 490–507.

Friedman, Benjamin M. 2014. “Has the financial crisis permanently changed the practice of monetary policy? Has it changed the theory of monetary policy?” NBER Working Paper No. 20128. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Gagnon, Joseph. 2016. “Quantitative easing: An underappreciated success,” Washington, D.C.: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

Furman, Jason. 2015. “Business investment in the United States: Facts, explanations, puzzles, and policies.” Remarks by Jason Furman, Chairman Council of Economic Advisers. Progressive Policy Institute.

Furman, J. (2016), “The new view of fiscal policy and its application”, Remarks at the Conference ‘Global Implications of Europe’s Redesign’, New York, 5 October 2016, https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/page/files/20161011_furman_suerf_fiscal_policy_cea .pdf

Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War. Princeton, US: Princeton University Press.

Hamilton, J. D. (forthcoming), ‘Why you should never use the Hodrick-Prescott filter’, Review of Economics and Statistics.

Hannsgen, G. (2004), ‘The transmission mechanism of monetary policy: A critical review’, Economics Working Paper No. 412, Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.

Herndon, T., Ash, M. & Pollin, R. (2014), ‘Does high public debt consistently stifle economic growth? a critique of Reinhart and Rogoff’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 38(2), 257–279.

Hervé, K., Pain, N., Richardson, P., Sédillot, F. & Beffy, P.-O. (2011), ‘The OECD’s new global model’, Economic Modelling 28(1-2), 589–601. ‘

Hetzel, R.L. and Leach, R.F. (2001), ‘The Treasury-Fed Accord: A new narrative account’, Economic Quarterly – Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, 87(1) 33-55.

Jayadev, A. & Konczal, M. (2011), ‘The stagnant labor market: some aspects of the bleak picture’, Journal of Post Keynesian EconomicsJ 33(3), 435–450.

Jayadev, A. & Mason, J. W. (2015), ‘Loose money, high rates: interest rate spreads in historical perspective’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 38(1), 93–130.

Jeon, Y. & Vernengo, M. (2008), ‘Puzzles, paradoxes, and regularities: Cyclical and structural productivity in the united states (1950–2005)’, Review of Radical Political Economics 40(3), 237–243.

Juniper, J., Sharpe, T. P. & Watts, M. J. (2014), ‘Modern monetary theory: contributions and critics’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 37(2), 281– 307.

Keynes, J. M. (2012), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes Volume 7, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.

Kogan, R., Stone, C., DaSilva, B. & Rejeski, J. (2015), ‘Difference between economic growth rates and treasury interest rates significantly affects long-term budget outlook,’ Center for Budget and Policy Priorities.

Krugman, Paul. 2016. “What Have We Learnt from the Crisis?” Presented at the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, Geneva: September 20. https://webspace.princeton.edu/users/ pkrugman/krugman_geneva.pdf

Leijonhufvud, A. (1984), ‘Capitalism and the factory system’, Diskussionsbeiträge, Serie A: Volkswirtschaftliche Beiträge, Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften und Statistik, Universität Konstanz.

Leijonhufvud, A. (2009), ‘Out of the corridor: Keynes and the crisis’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 33, 741–757.

Mason, J. (2017), ‘What recovery: The case for continued expansionary policy at the Fed’, Roosevelt Institute Working Paper.

Mason, J. & Jayadev, A. (2018), ‘A comparison of monetary and fiscal policy interaction under sound and functional finance regimes’, Metroeconomica 69(2), 488–508.

Mason, J. W. & Jayadev, A. (2015), ‘The post-1980 debt disinflation: an exercise in historical accounting’, Review of Keynesian Economics (3), 314–335.

Mathy, G. P. (2018), ‘Hysteresis and persistent long-term unemployment: The American Beveridge curve of the Great Depression and World War II’, Cliometrica 12(1), 127–152.

Mitchell, D. J. & Erickson, C. L. (2005), ‘Not yet dead at the fed: Unions, worker bargaining, and economy-wide wage determination’, Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 44(4), 565–606.

Okun, A. (1962), ‘Potential GNP: Its measurement and significance, Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 7, pp. 89–104.

Posen, Adam (2013),  ‘Cheap Talk Is No Alternative to Inflation Targeting’, in Is Inflation Targeting Dead? Central Banking After the Crisis, Centre for Economic Policy Research. London, UK: 59-65.

Price, David A (2012) ‘When the Fed Conducts Credit Policy’, Federal Reserve Region Focus (First Quarter). https://www.richmondfed.org/~/media/richmondfedorg/publications/research/region_focus/2012/q1/pdf/ federal_reserve.pdf

Reich, M. (2012), ‘The rising strength of management, high unemployment and slow growth: Revisiting Okun’s law’, Working Paper, Political Economy Research Institute.

Robinson, Joan (1937). Essays in the Theory of Employment. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Romer, C. D. (2007), Macroeconomic policy in the 1960s: The causes and consequences of a mistaken revolution,  talk at Lyndon B. Johnson Presidential Library, Economic History Association Annual Meeting, 2007.

Rosnick, D. (2016), ‘Potential for trouble: The IMF’s estimates of potential GDP’, Issue Brief, Center for Economic and Policy Research.

Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2013. “A Revolution in monetary policy: Lessons in the wake of the global financial crisis.” Presented at the 15th CD Deshmukh Memorial hosted by the Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai, India: January 3.

Storm, S. & Naastepad, C. (2013), Wage-led or profit-led supply: wages, productivity and investment, in M. Lavoie and E. Stockhammer eds., Wage-led growth: Concept, theories and policies, London: Palgrave MacMillan, pp. 100–124.

 

34 thoughts on “Macroeconomic Lessons from the Past Decade”

  1. “One school of heterodox thought, which has gained increasing prominence over the decade, holds that for a country like the United States, the existing public debt is never a constraint on fiscal policy.”
    I have a good guess at what this school is. But why can’t you mention the name of it? Other than that, I think you have a very nice chapter here. Thanks for posting it.

    1. There’s a lot of strong feelings around MMT that I’d rather not get into. The reference does make it clear that’s what I’m talking about.

      1. Hmn, I don’t know what to think of that. But anyways, there is a misspelling in this sentence- ” Iorward guidance appears even weaker; indeed, the idea that central banks can influence economic outcomes today by announcing policy changes somewhere in the future is “more theological than practical.”

        Not sure that is the kind of input you were looking for.

        1. Also, I have already quoted a sentence or two of your post on a different econ blog where I was arguing with Scott Sumner about something. And linked to your post. Hopefully that is ok.

          Speaking of that, might there be a reason to mention NGDP level targeting as a possibility for monetary policy in your paper?

          1. Of course it’s ok.

            Re NGDP targeting, I don’t think the problem is the choice of target, it’s the inability to reliably hit any macroeconomic target with the current instruments. Some people tell stories in which simply stating a different target makes policy (more) effective, but I think that requires very strong assumptions about expectations that I don’t think are applicable in a real world settings.

      2. Agree

        MMT has perhaps unfairly
        Taken on cult magic panacea status

        The management of state debt
        In a sovereign currency zone
        Starts with two often
        Avoided realities
        The sovereign can produce more currency at zero cost
        And the sovereign can control the nominal rate on state issued paper

        These two realities plus arithmetic
        Leads to fiscal liberation

        A liberation bourgeois society
        Restricts to war time
        But we can go there now

        1. Yes indeed.

          Arjun and I are working on a short piece saying essentially this – that the difference between MMT and orthodoxy is not about economics at all, in the sense of positive claims about how the world works — it’s about what we can reasonably expect from public authorities.

          I don’t think we need to bring currency into it, tho.

          1. Might i add
            Currency was the wrong word

            The implications of Money produced at zero real cost

            Takes time to work thru
            For citizen minds

            Crowding out is the Alamo last stand here

            Once demand inflation is
            Correctly discounted

            I liked your take on that btw
            In an earlier post

            MMTers are not wrong to talk about liberated fiscal action

            The line how do we pay for it

            Is counter one every time

            And the twin goblins of
            Tax hikes and higher
            cost of living

            These are agitprop campaign zones
            WHERE good MMTers
            Are excellent

          2. At the moment there is a surprisingly bitter spat between MMT people and the economic team advising the UK Labour Party. I’m struggling to grasp what substantive is at the root of it. Could it be that MMT people say that a permanent zero-interest rate policy is always desirable whilst more traditional leftists think that raising interest rates is desirable if inflation is high and unemployment very low?

          3. You are in luck — within the next 48 hours you will find here my analysis of what divides the MMT and the mainstream. Teaser: Less than both sides seem to think.

  2. One point I’d raise on the participation rate is the comparison with Canada. The baby boom demographics are similar, and there’s been a pretty steady convergence in patterns of economic activity. However, Canada did not have the big collapse in the participation rate, as we managed to avoid melting down to the same extent as the U.S.

    Would probably need more work to keep academics happy (no idea whether there’s any studies on this, but it seems like something the BoC might do), but it fits with your story about aggregate demand.

    1. I think that’s a good point. Canadians don’t seem all that different from US. Of course our President would probably say its because you’ve been taking advantage of us some way…

  3. You’ve got a typo in this sentence “Most heterodox as well as mainstream macroeconomic models suggess”

  4. Maybe it’s outside the scope of this, but it seems weird you don’t talk about taxes at all especially with a long section on sustainable debt. If increasing the deficit was a problem we could soak the rich and redistribute the money to people who actually spend it and still increase demand.

    1. Well, the peice was supposed to be about what we have learned from the past ten years. Have we learned anything about taxes and redistribution?

  5. Josh,

    Nice paper, worth studying more closely.

    I was surprised you didn’t make anything of income distribution trends to explain the demand gap. I would imagine this would be important.

    “Orthodox economic theory………is based on a framework in which economic problems are essentially about the allocation of scarce resources among competing ends. ”

    I can’t understand how orthodox theorists can mention neoclassic economics in the same sentence as macroeconomics. Over the last few days, I’ve been attempting to persuade David Glasner on his blog that this nexus is inappropriate.

    My powers of persuasion are very poor it seems.

      1. The demand gap is regulated thru credit flows

        You are right to target housing
        As the nearly hard wired infusion extraction target
        Summers famously said somewhere

        The new air for the tire doesn’t have to enter thru the puncture point

        Well no
        But as you point out the entery.point and the Extraction point
        Matter
        Hence one of yhe arguments

        For employee side pay roll tax cuts that.yes
        may not all be spent
        But leave the pattern of spending
        To householders

  6. Modern for profit
    Corporate wage based capitalism
    Is predicated
    on job and credit scarcity

    and
    firm
    Market power in the job credit and output markets

    This requires institutionally
    Contrived scarcity

    In particular
    managed over the cycle
    macro demand constraints

    Liberating social production from these
    Contrivance threatens corporate hegemony

    And the forces organized to prevent this liberation include
    The long term taboos
    Obeyed by orthodox social democracy

    The GODFATHER here is KALECKI

    a corporate dominated production system is indeed mediated by markets
    Both imperfect and even more crucially incomplete
    And incapable of spontaneous emergent market
    In particular macro
    CO ordination markets
    can not emerge they.must be imposed

    Here the GODFATHER IS LERNER
    Marco co ordination markets
    For
    Mark up
    Trade
    Investment
    Are crucial commanding heights objectives

    This is clearly the next stage in social planning of production

    But now

    We need first

    Maximum employment
    The GODFATHER HERE

    VICKREY

    THIS SHOULD BE THE FIRST STAGE
    OF ANY STRATEGY OF SOCIALISTS

    A FISCAL MECHANISM TO DRIVE
    A BORDERED DOMESTIC MARKET ECONOMY UP TO MAXIMUM EMPLOYMENT
    THE BEVERIDGE INVRSION POINT

    WHERE REAL OPENNINGS EXCEED
    APPLICANTS

  7. Stiglitz is very good on credit markets
    And rationing by standards
    Few bother to notice
    cutting rates while tightening standards is a common banks for profit pattern

    A credit drought during intervals of lower loan interest rates
    Is the reality of small and medium biz

    Truman
    They lend only to those who don’t need it

    Credit in public hands
    Run for macro impact
    would run the standards cycle
    not to directly react
    To the default rate cycle
    Which is the micro profit choice

    As defaults rise standards should loosen
    As they fall.standards should rise

    This is not what a bank level view leads to

    1. In the original version of this piece I had two questions following the three lessons. One was about the role of distribution, which just summarized the discussion here. The other was on exactly this issue – how important are changes in credit supply in the behavior of aggregate demand? I have to admit, I really am not sure what the lessons of the past decade are here. Intuitively, it makes sense that the financial crisis resticted credit to households and (some) businesses and perhaps local governemnts, and this played a big role in the downturn. But it’s surprisingly hard to find good evidence for this.

      ANyway, the chapter was over length and past deadline so I cut that stuff out. But it’s a question I’d like to come back to.

  8. ” It is quite literally a prehistoric argument to assert that central banks are engaged in experimental, unprecedented, or somehow scandalous and dangerous policy maneuvers today ”

    quite so

    a corollary is that the single policy rate is all that should be required when the commercial / investment / shadow banking system is allocating credit efficiently

    more radically interventionist CB policy is super-cyclical according to the evolution of banking systems that become under-capitalized relative to new risk eras

    that’s resolvable in theory through much more competent capital and risk regulation

  9. he single policy rate is all that should be required when the commercial / investment / shadow banking system is allocating credit efficiently

    Sorry, I can’t go along with this.

    First of all, “efficiently” is just not a word you should use here. When used in a policy context, it’s almost inherently dishonest since it confuses a technical property in a formal setting with some broader but unstated criteria of desirability or effectiveness. Bluntly, I don’t think the phrase “allocating credit efficiently” means anything at all outside of some toy model.

    Second, the goal of macroeconomic policy is to change the overall level of activity in the economy. Doing this through a single monetary policy lever depnds both on (a) the degree to which the financial system’s ability to extend credit depends on the actions of the central bank and (b) the degree to which the spending of nonfinancial units depends on their access to credit. Financial innovation makes banks and other institutions less dependent on any particular lever the central bank relies on. The classic historical case is the way reserve requirements gradually became irrelevant in the 1970s and 80s. The idea that the central bank can “set the interest rate” in any economically meaningful sense should not be taken for granted.

    1. I’m using the word “efficient” in the context of the relationship of the commercial banking system to the central bank. I’m taking it as a given that there is a private or commercial banking system. Relative to the imagined counterfactual of a government run “central bank only” system, the government delegates almost the entire task of banking to the private sector, using the central bank a minimalist control level according to efficiency. In this context, the commercial banking system is an extension of the CB, deliberately designed for active competition instead of socialized allocation of capital to risk.

      QE and all of its credit risk variations is a symptom of radical inefficiency. Banks don’t need those reserves if the system is working as intended. It’s a sloppy insurance buffer, indicative of capital malfunction.

      The Fed system worked for a long time with relatively miniscule excess reserves. Then it didn’t.

      Notwithstanding the refusal of monetarists to think of monetary policy in terms of interest rates, the anchor role of the CB is to set a policy interest rate. The treasury yield curve, credit spreads, and the allocation of commercial bank capital to risk follows from that in an efficiently running competitive system. The progressive digitalization of bank balance sheet management operations means that outsized excess reserves are not necessary in an efficiently running system, and it also means that monetarism as conventionally described is a joke.

      This got messed up starting in 2008. I guess it did in the 1930’s as well.

      Those were extraordinary interruptions to the efficient working of the system.

      1. according to efficiency.

        I don’t know what these words mean.

        Monetarism is wrong, agreed. But I don’t know that that tells us much about what is right.

  10. I’m using the word “efficiency” in the sense of a ratio of output to input. I don’t think that’s incorrect at all as a rough idea. And I’m using it specifically in the context of QE as an indicator of a banking system monetary environment that was operating at a level of extreme inefficiency. One can gauge that level of inefficiency by comparing the quantum of QE excess reserves to the pre-crisis level. It’s astronomically multiplicative and therefore inefficient in quantitative terms – using that quantum of excess reserves as the denominator of efficiency when it comes to the usefulness of that forced system input. Banks don’t generally need those reserves. Moreover, QE (and its credit risk variations) and the bloated reserves it created in my view is the iconic indictor of the CB response to the crisis.

    This is a specific, somewhat narrow observation and characterization. Apart from that, and including that, I don’t believe I written anything that disagrees with your paper.

    However, I’d say that a good deal more can be accomplished by capital and risk regulation that sensibly anticipates stress points. Moreover, such regulation doesn’t require the central bank assume responsibility for it. Canada is a far superior model for central bank and regulation than the United States – in my view – and relative performance during the financial crisis would not be inconsistent with that view. The argument being that the CB shouldn’t be doing two different jobs the way the Fed does.

  11. I am counting down the hours for this explanation you promised. About what divides MMT from the ‘mainstream’ and why it isn’t such a big deal. Been about 6 hours since I saw your reply to either Stone or Paine (not really able to determine which, and can’t quite figure the time stamp on this blog). I hope it is good and I hope it explains why you won’t mention those three letters in your chapter. So within 42 hours?

    1. Ok, 4 hours ahead of NY time at the moment. Are you writing from Eastern Greenland or Iceland? Or is it one of those daylight savings time disruptions that has me discombobulated?

        1. Thank you Professor. One thing I have noticed is that MMT pretty firmly rejects any kind of ‘loanable funds’ argument or thinking. Investment requiring a prior pool of savings and similar ideas. Rejects any ‘financial crowding out’ caused by deficit spending also, (or the bond issuing that may accompany it). Their understanding of banking operations also seems to differ from mainstream. Maybe that is covered under the endogenous money idea or under the idea that the central bank can set the interest rate it wants. Or maybe it just isn’t all that important. What do you think?

  12. I’m also really looking forward to your analysis of the UK Labour Party economics team vs MMT spat. Something I’ve wondered about is whether part of the disagreement stems from how far each side believes redistribution of relative income would increase demand due to poorer people having a greater propensity to spend. You seem to be saying here that you think that effect has been overstated. I guess John McDonnell’s team believes that measures such as sector-wide-collective-bargaining, rent controls, redirection of taxation towards the more affluent etc etc would create ample aggregate demand such that fiscal deficits were much less necessary. By contrast their MMT “adversaries” don’t believe that?
    There also seems to be a thread to the argument along the lines that it is extremely dangerous to use the same language as the “neo-liberals” purporting that fiscal balance is a virtue etc. So MMT people are saying that irrespective of what is actually done, it really matters how that is talked about.

    1. I don’t have a take on the spat specifically – my piece is at a hogher level of abstraction, on the MMT view of public budgets vs the mainstream. (I don’t know enough about UK politics anyway.) But my view is that there are no major differences in analysis (as opposed to practical judgements) between MMT and the mainstream. So in that sense I guess I’m on the side of Wren-Lewis and co.

Comments are closed.