Net and Gross, or What We Can and Cannot Learn from Balance Sheets

One of the less acknowledged of the secret sins of economists, it seems to me, is the failure to distinguish between net and gross quantities, or to treat the net numbers if they were all that mattered. Case in point, the issue of deleveraging, where the good guys — the anti-austerians — are trying to get an accounting-identity argument to do more work than it it’s capable of. A good example is this post from Peter Dorman (which Krugman liked), which points out that in a closed economy one agent’s debt is always another agent’s asset, and total consumption must equal total income. So the only way that one agent can reduce its net liabilities is for another’s to increase, just as the only way some agents can spend less than their income is for others to spend more. In this sense increased public debt is just the flipside of private-sector deleveraging; arguments that the public sector should reduce its debt along with the private sector are incoherent. QED, right? Except, this argument proves too much. It’s true that one agent’s net financial position can’t improve unless another’s gets worse. But the same accounting logic also means that financial claims across the whole economy always sum to zero. Total net worth is always equal to the sum of tangible assets, no matter what happens on the financial side. [1] So it’s not clear what leveraging and develeraging could even mean in these terms. So, since the words evidently do mean something, it seems they’re not being used in those terms. It seems to me that when people talk about (de)leveraging, they are almost always talking about gross financial claims, not net, relative to income. A unit that adds $1,000 in debt and acquires a financial asset valued at $1,000 is more leveraged than it was before. And in this gross sense, it is perfectly possible for the public and private sector to simultaneously deleverage. Consider the following very simple economy, with just two agents:

T1
Income Assets Liabilities Net Worth
A 1 4 3 1
B 1 5 2 3
Total 2 9 5 4
T2
Income Assets Liabilities Net Worth
A 1 3 2 1
B 1 4 1 3
Total 2 7 3 4

The transition from T1 to T2 involves simultaneous deleveraging — in the economically meaningful sense — by both the agents in the economy, and no national accounting identities are violated. What would this look like in practice? To some extent, it could simply mean netting out offsetting financial claims, but that only really works within the financial sector; nonfinancial actors don’t generally hold financial assets and liabilities at the same time without some good institutional reason. (A firm may both receive and extend trade credit, but those two lines on the balance sheet can’t be netted out unless we want to go back to a cash-on-the-barrelhead economy. A typical middle-class household has both retirement savings and a mortgage and student-loan debt; both the borrowing and saving are sufficiently subsidized and tax-favored that it makes sense to add to the IRA rather than paying off the debt. [2]) To the extent that this kind of deleveraging does take place within the nonfinancial sector, it requires that units reduce their gross saving, i.e. their acquisition of financial assets — a suggestion that will seem even more paradoxical to conventional wisdom than the claim that private-sector deleveraging requires increased public debt. [3] But there’s another approach. Most borrowing by households and nonfinancial firms and households is undertaken to finance the acquisition of a tangible asset — in the table above, we should really divide the assets column into tangible assets and financial assets. For the low net worth units, most assets are tangible; for middle-class households, the house is by far the biggest asset, while property, plant and equipment is generally the biggest item on the asset side of a nonfinancial firm’s balance sheet. So the most natural way for the private sector and the public sector to deleverage is through a transfer of tangible assets from debtor to creditor units, combined with the extinction of the debts associated with the assets. This is, in essence, what privatization of public assets is supposed to do, when the IMF imposes it as part of a structural adjustment program. And more to the point, it’s what the foreclosure process, in its herky-jerky way, is doing in the housing market. At the end of the road, there’s a lot less mortgage debt — and a lot more big suburban landlords. [4] And the private sector has reduced its leverage, without any increase in the public sector’s. (Of course, we could just extinguish the debt and skip the asset-transfer part. But that default could be a means of deleveraging is one of those thoughts you’re not allowed to have.) Now, all this said, I completely agree with Dorman’s conclusion, that reducing public debt would hinder rather than help deleveraging. (Or rather, what he thinks is his conclusion; the real logic of his argument is that nothing can help or hinder deleveraging, since — like motion — it does not exist.) But the reason has nothing to do with balance sheets. It is because I believe that fiscal consolidation will reduce aggregate income — the denominator in leverage. I reckon Dorman (and Krugman) would agree. But this an empirical claim, not one that can be deduced from national accounting identities.
[1] Or the sum of tangible assets and base money, if you don’t treat the latter as a liability of the government. This is a question that gets people remarkably worked up, but it’s not important to this argument. (Or to any other, as far as I can tell.) [2] Actually I suspect many middle-class households are saving more than is rational — they’re acquiring financial assets when paying down debt would have a higher return. But anyone who knows me knows how comically unsuited I am to have opinions on anyone else’s personal finances. [3] Reducing debt and and expenditure simultaneously doesn’t help, since one unit’s expenditure is another’s income. For financial deleveraging to work, people really do have to save less. [4] Who might or might not end up being the banks themselves.

6 thoughts on “Net and Gross, or What We Can and Cannot Learn from Balance Sheets”

  1. Hey Josh, Very interesting, but not sure I understand fully (I might be being dense). Are you essentially saying that we could reduce debt by doing a debt-equity swap (i.e. for eg. high net-worth units-landlords get equity in defaulting houses, thereby extinguishing the debt contract?). If not, if this is a purchase of the asset at current value, does this not require a reduction in income on the part of the new landlord to be or a drawing down of his other assets to purchase the debt?

    Finally, in the real world, given that debt often fuels income, why does income remain constant in your example?

    cheers
    Arjun

  2. You're not being dense. I'm trying to figure this stuff out as I write, so it's not presented as clearly as it could be.

    The point of the numerical example is just to show that it is perfectly possible for every sector of an economy to reduce leverage simultaneously without violating any accounting identities, once you define leverage (correctly) as the ratio of gross debt to income.

    In the housing case, yes, I'm thinking of a debt equity swap. Say the household owns a house worth $100,000 and owes $100,000 of mortgage debt to the bank. Now the house is transferred from the household to the bank, and the mortgage is extinguished. So the household is less leveraged — its liabilities and its assets have both fallen by $100,000, while its income is unchanged (by this particular transaction). The bank's balance sheet looks the same as it did before — a $100,000 financial asset (the mortgage) has been replaced with a $100,000 tangible asset (the house). So again, this is a case of overall deleveraging — one unit has reduced its leverage and no one's leverage has increased. And of course the bank could in turn sell the house and use the proceeds to pay down its own debt; provided the sale was at least partially for cash, that would produce further deleveraging.

    Now you are right, in the real world this process is likely to result in lower incomes, which will offset the deleveraging happening on the balance sheet, maybe even cancel it out completely. But that fall in income is not a balance-sheet phenomenon. Whether the foreclosed-on household loses wage income, reduces consumption, etc. are behavioral questions — you can't learn anything about them from accounting identities. That's my point at the end.

  3. I guess a pithier version of this post would be that Keynesians often say that the only way to reduce leverage is to reduce expenditure relative to income, but for some units to do that other units have to increase expenditure relative to income by the same amount. The second half is true but the first half is not. You can also reduce leverage by swapping debt for equity (or equivalently by transferring tangible assets from debtors to creditors), or (the good way) by raising income.

    What I don't know is how important these debt-equity swaps are in practice. Even if every household that's behind in its mortgage was foreclosed on, would that significantly reduce aggregate household leverage?

  4. This is what I have been looking for. This way of putting it makes it easier to understand and really interesting to read. Nicely done. Good job with this.
    llc

Comments are closed.