CBO Interest Rate Forecasts, 2011-2019

This is just a brief addition to the previous post. I should have included this figure, which shows the CBO’s 10-year forecasts for the interest rate on the 10-year Treasury bond, compared with the actual interest rate.

Forecasts by year made. Source: CBO 10-Year Economic Projections, various years

One obvious point here is that, for most of the past decade, the CBO has been projecting a return of interest rates to “normal” levels, which has stubbornly failed to take place. If we compare the interest rate on Treasury bonds at any point since 2010 to the CBO’s forecasts from a couple years before, the actual interest rate is lower than the forecast. This is especially true in the earlier years.

Another point, more relevant to my post, is the latest adjustment really is a big deal. While there have been comparable downward adjustments, there haven’t been any in a while; in fact for the past four years the long-run forecast has been fixed around 3.7 percent.1 This is also the first interest rate forecast since the recession that predicts that interest rates will remain near current levels indefinitely. Of course, it may still end up being an overestimate, if the recent decline in rates continues.

One takeaway is that when trying to guess what interest rates will be in the future, you probably can’t do better than assuming that they’ll be more or less where current rates are. There have been many, many confident predictions over the past decade that interest rates will soon rise — the CBO is far from the worst offender here — and they have consistently been proven wrong. If you want to talk about the future path of government debt, or some similar question where interest rates matter, you need a very good reason to assume interest rates much higher than what we see today. A strong feeling that interest rates just have to go up someday, isn’t enough. And as long as interest rates remain close to current levels, the debt ratio is not going to go up very much, even with deficits significantly larger than today’s.

I should note that while I think pictures like this are clarifying, I don’t find that they’re always effective rhetorically. People who are committed to some variety of hard-money view find it easy to say, “well sure, predictions of rising rates have been wrong for many years. But how do you know they won’t be right this time?”

* * *

If you’re just interested in the policy debate, you can stop reading here. But I can’t help pointing to another takeaway, from a more theoretical perspective: This picture is clearly not the result of a process where expected value of a variable is just an unbiased estimate of its true future value. In that case the errors should be distributed at random around the actual path, instead of all way off to one side.2

To be sure, the CBO’s numbers are not forecasts in a strict sense, but inputs into its legally mandated projections of the future path of the debt. The CBO needs to make forecasts in a way that minimizes not just ex post errors, but challenges to is credibility and neutrality. The relevant question is not whether the forecasts are as accurate as they can be, but whether they are “reasonable” in some broader sense. And this is as it should be! If I were dictator of the CBO, I would not insist on using forecast values that I myself think will be closest to the true values, but would balance this against the need for a consistent and transparent methodology and the costs of getting too far from the views of the relevant community of experts. The CBO is not simply a machine for generating forecasts, it plays a specific role in a concrete political process.

But of course, this isn’t just the CBO. Any institution operates on the basis of a set of shared beliefs about the world, and the process by which those beliefs are generated needs to be compatible with the other activities and reproduction of the institution. In any setting where people have to act collectively, getting as accurate as possible a picture of the relevant facts needs to be weighed against the need for some picture that everyone can agree on. Which, from the point of view of economics, suggests we need to think more carefully about expectations. We need to distinguish between the “expected” value as the central tendency of a given probability distribution; the subjective belief in someone’s head about the likely outcome; and the implicit belief about the outcome that is the basis of the relevant behavior. The essence of the rational expectations revolution was to collapse these three senses into the first one, effectively removing expectations as an independent object of inquiry.


For anyone interested, here is the R code that generates the above figure. I think including the relevant code whenever you present quantitative results is best practice, for blogs as much as anywhere else.

# can update this as new projections become available
files <- c('https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2018-06/51135-2011-08-economicprojections.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2018-06/51135-2012-08-economicprojections.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51135-2013-02-economicprojections.xls',
'https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51135-2014-08-economicprojections.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51135-2015-08-economicprojections.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51135-2016-08-economicprojections-2.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/recurringdata/51135-2017-06-economicprojections2.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2018-08/51135-2018-08-economicprojections.xlsx',
'https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2019-08/51135-2019-08-economicprojections_1.xlsx')
# using the August reports where available. For some reason there's none in summer 2013.

n <- length(files)
cbo.projections <- list()

for (i in 1:n) {
temp <- tempfile()
download.file(files[i], temp)
x <- read.xlsx(temp, sheetIndex = 3)
unlink(temp)
cbo.projections[[i]] <- x
}

names(cbo.projections) <- 2011:2019

cbo.interest <- as.data.frame(matrix(nrow=n*2, ncol=12))
names(cbo.interest) <- c('forecast.year', paste0('y', 1:11))
cbo.interest[,1] <- rep(2011:2019, each=2)

s <- c(7, 7, 8, rep(7, n-3))
# for some reason in 2013 the data starts one column further over.

for (i in 1:n){
x <- cbo.projections[[i]]
yearrow <- subset(x, x[,4]=='Units', select=s[i]:(s[i]+10))
interestrow <- subset(x, x[,2]=='10-Year Treasury Note', select=s[i]:(s[i]+10))
for (j in 1:11){
cbo.interest[i*2-1, j+1] <- levels(yearrow[1,j])[yearrow[1,j]]
cbo.interest[i*2, j+1] <- levels(interestrow[1,j])[interestrow[1,j]]
}

}

interest <- read.delim('https://fred.stlouisfed.org/data/GS10.txt', skip=16, sep =' ')[,-2:-3]
names(interest) <- c('date', 'GS10')
interest$year <- substr(interest$date, 1, 4)
interest.ann <- aggregate(interest$GS10, by=list(interest$year), FUN=mean)

y1 <- 2010
y2 <- 2029

plot(x=y1:y2, y =y1:y2, ylim=c(0,6), xlab='', ylab='Projected Interest Rate')
for (i in seq(1, n*2, by=2)){
lines(x=cbo.interest[i,-1], y=cbo.interest[i+1,-1], col=rainbow(n*2)[i])
}
lines(x=2010:2019, y=interest.ann[58:67,2], lwd=2)
legend(x='bottomright', legend = 2011:2019, col=rainbow(n*2)[seq(1, n*2, by=2)], bty='n', lty=1, ncol=2)
title(main='CBO forecasts for the 10-Year Treasury Bond, 2011-2019')
# the correct thing to do here would be to convert the data to long format and produce the plot with ggplot.
# would be simpler and give prettier results. But this works and I am too lazy to redo it.

 

  1. The CBO generally makes two forecasts a year; the exceptional size of the current adjustment would be even clearer if I showed all of them, instead of just one per year. But that would make the figure too cluttered.
  2. People who have been exposed to an economics education may be tempted to reply that, yes, the interest rate in 2015 was 2.1 percent, but the true expected value of the 2015 rate as of 2013 was still 3.5 percent. It’s hard to convey how insane this way of thinking is.

3 thoughts on “CBO Interest Rate Forecasts, 2011-2019”

  1. The question is: why should the interst rate increase? What determines the interest rate?

    I can think of at least 3 different explanations:

    1) Natural level: if we assume that there is some sort of natural level of the interest rate, and that this natural level is linked to the natural level of the profit rate, which in turn depends on some technological hocus pocus about labor/capital subsitution, then you would expect the interest rate to bounce back after some time it is low. I( think this is the basic assumption underlying the idea that the interest rate has to bounce back.

    2) Credibility: as the debt to GDP ratio of the USA increases, savers might fear a government bankruptcy pushing rates higer. This is what happened to Greece and Italy but, first of all Greece and Italy have to behave under some artificial limits that the USA doesn’t have, and second savers don’t have many other places in which to put their savings.

    3) Saving/investiment mismatch: if as I believe we are in a cronic underconsumption situation where ex ante saving desires are much higer than invetiment opportunities (due to hig income inequality and a model of invetiment opportunities that doesn’t assume that investors will just go on investing until the profit rate reaches 0), then the “natural” interest rate is pushed towards 0 due to an excess of savings, and central banks have to act this way otherwise they would trigger a recession.

    If 3 is the correct explanation then the potential problem lies in bubbles and in a general increase of the wealth to income ratio, so looking to the government debt/GDP ratio doesn’t tell the full story.

  2. Late arrival indeed

    BUT seems clear social net positive accumulation will proceed without
    Scarcity rent payments

    Proposal zero real policy

    on sovereign safe rate

    And issue consoles

    1. Zero *real* rates? That’s hard money, my friend, and we won’t have it around here. Zero nominal risk-free rate forever. And the rentiers should thank us it’s not negative.

Comments are closed.